Monday, February 2, 2009

lacks any comparative advantage in managing vast and complex financial institutions

From Portfolio:
"
5 Steps to Fix the Banks
Guest Commentary: Pulling banks out of their apparent death spiral won't be easy. But these simple principles should frame the debate.
rebuilding banks
As the liquidity crisis continues, the problem is clear—it's the solution that remains opaque.

The problem with the U.S. banking system is simple: It's largely insolvent. Banks have far too little capital to supply the credit needed to finance recovery let alone growth.

The insolvency problem is centered around so-called "toxic" or troubled assets that banks hold in great amount and which are today worth far less than cost—generally securitized residential home loans.

But the problem of insolvency is centered around toxic assets only in the sense that the problem of a burning house is "centered" around the place the fire started.

As Congressman Henry Steagall said the last time we faced a severe depression, once a fire is raging, the most important issue is how to put it out—not to locate the point of origin.

The United States must provide "rescue capital" to its banks and needs to do so now because private capital markets cannot. However, rescue capital should be provided only on terms that maximize the prospect of recovering it along with a full and fair return. Governmental capital must not be provided to subsidize current investors in these institutions or to relieve the institutions themselves from past errors.

How then can we swiftly recapitalize the banking system? Here are five simple principles that should guide the effort:

  1. If a bank is nearing insolvency (or is already insolvent) and seeks rescue capital from the government, that capital should be provided only on terms at least as favorable to taxpayers as those that a stable and thriving private capital market would demand. In other words, we should insist on terms at least as favorable as those that private investors typically demand to refinance an imperiled business trying to avoid liquidation in normal economic circumstances.

    If new capital is not available to banks from private sources, including importantly rights offerings addressed to their incumbent shareholders, then the rescue capital provided by government must obtain at least the rights and preferences that fresh capital routinely receives in workouts.


  2. These structural terms are well understood and certainly include:

    • Full and preferential recovery of all new capital along with a risk-adjusted rate of return before anything is paid to incumbent or "dead" capital

    • Governance controls and rights giving the new capital a super-majority of seats on the board of directors that shifts to the providers of the new money the right to control the hiring, firing and compensation of executives and, in particular, the CEO and senior leadership team and

    • The right of the board to sell or merge the business with a "times-money" liquidation preference in favor of new capital.

    There is no basis for providing fresh capital to imperiled banks without these traditional and routine terms.


  3. The government should not acquire toxic or troubled assets at above-market prices. Doing so is perverse. Such a policy provides new risk capital in direct proportion to the recipient's past foolish investment decisions.

    Buying mortgage-backed securities at a premium to market, for example, is payment for error—the banks with the largest holdings of the worst assets and their incumbent investors get a larger subsidy than do those that resisted such assets. That makes no sense and not only creates moral hazard—it celebrates it.


  4. Rescue finance under these standard terms is far superior to formal nationalization or receivership when that means assuming total direct operating control of institutions as complex as, say, Citibank or Bank of America—especially if the goal is to immediately empower those institutions to lend again.

    The government has its hands full and, in any event, lacks any comparative advantage in managing vast and complex financial institutions. The board of each bank rescued should hire, motivate and compensate independent senior executives, not government employees, to run the bank.


  5. There must be a clear and immutable deadline for banks to seek governmental rescue finance. The rescue program must force the banks immediately to come to terms with their financial condition and end the appearance of solvency which leads to dangerous "last period" problems and, in any event, doesn't provide needed liquidity.

    If an imperiled bank cannot obtain the capital it needs from the private market it must seek rescue capital from the government right now—say in the 60 to 90 days following the launch of a rescue finance program. After that, insolvency means seizure and liquidation or forced merger, all without prospect of any financial recovery for incumbent investors.

    This mandatory pressure is designed to avoid banks trying to hang on in the hope things will somehow work out for their investors. We need well-capitalized banks to create liquidity and we need them now.

If the government follows these simple principles we may be able to create a solvent banking system swiftly enough to prevent a long depression. If we succeed, the U.S. and its citizens get repaid fully for the risk taken before incumbent investors recover anything.

These are the standard terms, and we have no time to waste.

No comments: